TWN
Info Service on Finance and Development (May22/01)
18 May 2022
Third World Network
When saviours are the problem
Published in SUNS #9578 dated 18 May 2022
Sydney/Kuala Lumpur, 17 May (IPS/Anis Chowdhury and Jomo Kwame
Sundaram*) -- Central bank policies have often worsened economic crises
instead of resolving them. By raising interest rates in response to
inflation, they often exacerbate, rather than mitigate business cycles
and inflation.
NEITHER GODS NOR MAESTROS
US Federal Reserve Bank chair Jerome Powell has admitted: "Whether
we can execute a soft landing or not, it may actually depend on factors
that we don't control."
He conceded, "What we can control is demand, we can't really
affect supply with our policies. And supply is a big part of the story
here". Hence, decision-makers must consider more appropriate
policy tools.
Rejecting "one size fits all" formulas, including simply
raising interest rates, anti-inflationary measures should be designed
as appropriate. Instead of squelching demand by raising interest rates,
supply could be enhanced. Thus, Milton Friedman - whom many central
bankers still worship - blamed the 1930s' Great Depression on the
US Fed. Instead of providing liquidity support to businesses struggling
with short-term cash-flow problems, it squeezed credit, crushing economic
activity.
Similarly, before becoming Fed chair, Ben Bernanke's research team
concluded, "an important part of the effect of oil price shocks
[in the 1970s] on the economy results not from the change in oil prices,
per se, but from the resulting tightening of monetary policy".
Adverse impacts of the 1970s' oil price shocks were worsened by the
reactions of monetary policymakers, which caused stagflation. That
is, US Fed and other central bank interventions caused economic stagnation
without mitigating inflation.
Likewise, the longest US recession after the Great Depression, during
the 1980s, was due to interest rate hikes by Fed chair Paul Volcker.
A recent New York Times op-ed warned, "The Powell pivot to tighter
money in 2021 is the equivalent of Mr. Volcker's 1981 move" and
"the 2020s economy could resemble the 1980s".
MONETARY POLICY FOR SUPPLY SHOCKS?
Food prices surged in 2011 due to weather-related events ruining harvests
in major food producing nations, such as Australia and Russia. Meanwhile,
fuel prices soared with political turmoil in the Middle East. However,
Boston Fed head Eric Rosengren argued, "tightening monetary policy
solely in response to contractionary supply shocks would likely make
the impact of the shocks worse for households and businesses".
Referring to Boston Fed research, he noted that commodity price changes
did not affect the long-run inflation rate.
Other research has also concluded that commodity price shocks are
less likely to be inflationary. This reduced inflationary impact has
been attributed to "structural changes" such as workers'
diminished bargaining power due to labour market deregulation, technological
innovation and globalization.
Hence, central banks are no longer expected to respond strongly to
food and fuel price increases. Policymakers should not respond aggressively
to supply shocks - often symptomatic of broader macroeconomic developments.
Instead, central banks should identify the deeper causes of food and
fuel price rises, only responding appropriately to them. Wrong policy
responses can compound, rather than mitigate problems.
APPROPRIATE INNOVATIONS
A former Philippines central bank Governor Amando M. Tetangco, Jr
noted that it had not responded strongly to higher food and fuel prices
in 2004. He stressed, "authorities should ignore changes in the
price of things that they cannot control".
Tetangco warned, "the required policy response is not... straightforward...
Thus policy makers will need to make a choice between bringing down
inflation and raising output growth". He emphasized, "a
real sector supply side response may be more appropriate in addressing
the pressure on prices".
Thus, instead of restricting credit indiscriminately, financing constraints
on desired industries (e.g., renewable energy) should be eased. Enterprises
deemed inefficient or undesirable - e.g., polluters or those engaged
in speculation - should have less access to the limited financing
available.
This requires designing macroeconomic policies to enable dynamic new
investments, technologies and economic diversification. Instead of
reacting with blunt interest rate policy tools, policymakers should
know how fiscal and monetary policy tools interact and impact various
economic activities. Used well, these can unlock supply bottlenecks,
promote desired investments and enhance productivity. As no one size
fits all, each policy objective will need appropriate, customized,
often innovative tools.
LESSONS FROM CHINA
China's central bank, the People's Bank of China (PBOC), developed
"structural monetary policy" tools and new lending programmes
to help victims of COVID-19. These ensured ample inter-bank liquidity,
supported credit growth, and strengthened domestic supply chains.
Outstanding loans to small and micro businesses rose 25% to 20.8 trillion
renminbi by March 2022 from a year before. By January, the interest
rate for loans to over 48 million small and medium enterprises had
dropped to 4.5%, the lowest level since 1978.
The PBOC has also provided banks with loan funds for promising, innovative
and creditworthy companies, e.g., involved in renewable energy and
digital technologies. It thus achieves three goals: fostering growth,
maintaining debt at sustainable levels, and "green transformation".
Defying global trends, China's "factory-gate" (or producer
price) inflation fell to a one-year low in April 2022 as the PBOC
eased supply chains and stabilized commodity prices.
Although consumer prices have risen with COVID-19 lockdowns, the increases
have remained relatively benign so far. In short, the PBOC has coordinated
monetary policy with both fiscal and industrial policies to boost
confidence, promote desired investments and achieve stable growth.
It maintains financial stability and policy independence by regulating
capital flows, thus avoiding sudden outflows, and interest rate hikes
in response.
IMPROVING POLICY COORDINATION
Central bankers monitor aggregate indicators, such as wages growth.
However, before reacting to upward wage movements, the context needs
to be considered. For example, wages may have stagnated, or the labour
share of income may have declined over the long-term.
Moreover, wage increases may be needed for critical sectors facing
shortages to attract workers with relevant skills. Wage growth itself
may not be the problem. The issue may be weak long-term productivity
growth due to deficient investments. Input-output tables can provide
information about sectoral bottlenecks and productivity, while flow-of-funds
information reveals what sectors are financially constrained, and
which are net savers or debtors.
Such information can helpfully guide the design of appropriate, complementary
fiscal and monetary policy tools. Undoubtedly, pursuing heterodox
policies is challenging in the face of policy fetters imposed by current
orthodoxies.
Central bank independence - with dogmatic mandates for inflation targeting
and capital account liberalization - precludes better coordination,
e.g., between fiscal and monetary authorities. It also undercuts the
policy space needed to address both demand- and supply-side inflation.
Monetary authorities are under tremendous pressure to be seen to be
responding to rising prices. But experience reminds us they can easily
make things worse by acting inappropriately. The answer is not greater
central bank independence, but rather, improved economic policy coordination.
[* Anis Chowdhury, Adjunct Professor at Western Sydney University
(Australia), held senior United Nations positions in New York and
Bangkok. Jomo Kwame Sundaram, a former economics professor, was United
Nations Assistant Secretary-General for Economic Development, and
received the Wassily Leontief Prize for Advancing the Frontiers of
Economic Thought in 2007.]