|
TWN Info Service
on WTO and Trade Issues (Apr07/02)
02 April 2007
Projected Doha Round
benefits hinge on misleading trade models
Published in SUNS #6214 dated 20 March 2007
Lance Taylor and Rudiger von Arnim*
The World Trade Organization's Doha Round of multilateral trade negotiations,
named because it originated in the capital of Qatar, has collapsed as
of this writing. Negotiators have been unable to reach agreement in
the face of repeatedly missed deadlines. Despite this stalemate, many
believe that negotiations may be revived.
Whether Doha is revived or not, there are decided differences of opinion
regarding the likely benefits, and beneficiaries, of a new round of
tariff reductions. Proponents of a Doha revival claim that there will
be significant global benefits. But others suggest that benefits will
be marginal, and that they will be significantly different for developed,
developing, and the least developed countries.
They will also affect specific industries differently. Recent research
done by the authors and others suggests that some developing nations
may be made worse off as a result of an agreement.(Polaski, Sandra.
(2006). "Winners and Losers: The Impact of the Doha Round on Developing
Countries". Washington: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace;
Taylor, Lance and Rudiger von Arnim. (2006). "Modelling the Impact
of Trade Liberalization: A Critique of Computable General Equilibrium
Models" Oxford UK: Oxfam International.)
The principal concern of this paper is that projected welfare gains
from trade liberalization are derived from global computable general
equilibrium (CGE) models, which are based on highly unrealistic assumptions.
CGE models have become the main tool for economic analysis of the benefits
of multilateral trade liberalization; therefore, it is essential that
these models be scrutinized for their realism and relevance. In this
SCEPA Policy Note, we analyse the foundation of CGE models and argue
that their predictions are often misleading. We find that any possible
Doha trade agreement is likely to introduce substantial macroeconomic
risk for developing countries, and particularly sub-Saharan Africa.
The Players
One reason why it has been so difficult to reach a new WTO agreement
is that there are three major negotiating blocs with different economic
characteristics and, therefore, different trade interests. The developed
world, represented by the member countries of the OECD, aims to maintain
its traditionally high protection for agriculture while demanding improved
market access in developing countries for agriculture, manufacturing,
and services exports.
The large developing countries such as India, Brazil,(in 2004, India
and Brazil joined the United States, the EU and Australia to form the
core negotiating group of the Five Interested Parties, FIPs) and Argentina
hope to reach an agreement that allows protection as well as development
policies in those sectors, and a substantial reduction in developed
countries' agricultural tariffs and subsidies. The poorest countries,
whose small economies are often heavily dependent on foreign aid and
a few primary commodity and agricultural exports, feel the need to defend
preferential trade agreements and to promote exports and economic diversification,
while demanding special protection against increased import competition.
CGE Models and Their Limitations
Estimating the benefits or "welfare gains" from trade liberalization
is a difficult task. Countries produce a wide range of goods and services
and trade them amongst each other. The costs of their production, the
availability of their resources and inventories, and the accessibility
and quality of their labour varies widely. In sum, as economists would
put it, we generally know little about the shape and location of supply-
and demand-schedules.
CGE models aim to calculate such benefits, and begin with a consistent
accounting framework called the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM). Economic
theory then brings the accounting to life using behavioural equations
to estimate the direction and impact of a "shock" to the system,
such as the removal or reduction of a tariff or subsidy. In addition,
each CGE model requires "closure" assumptions that define
the direction of causality among variables. (Taylor, Lance, and Lysy,
Frank J., 1979, "Vanishing Income Redistributions: Keynesian Clues
About Model Surprises in the Short Run." Journal of Development
Economics, 6, pp. 11-29; Taylor 2004, "Reconstructing Macroeconomics:
Structuralist Proposals and Critiques of the Mainstream", Cambridge
Massachusetts, Harvard University Press).
Just like the parameters of the behavioural equations, these so called
"closure assumptions" are chosen by the individual modeler,
and have a significant effect on the size and the direction of the projected
welfare changes.
Parameter values strongly influence results, and this is precisely the
problem. The size of the potential welfare gains from trade liberalization
depends on the assumptions made in choosing the reactions and influences
among the variables. More precisely, the gains depend on the elasticity
parameter and the characteristic bend and slope of a schedule. The magnitude
of the trade elasticities is of critical importance for simulation results,
and the World Bank has been rightly criticized for using unusually high
elasticities that lack empirical support. (Ackerman, Frank. (2005).
"The Shrinking Gains from Trade: A Critical Assessment of Doha
Round Projections." Working Paper).
Small Gains, Real Losses: World Bank Estimates and Their Assumptions
The most recent World Bank estimates predict roughly $287 billion in
global welfare gains over time as a result of a Doha agreement.(Anderson,
Kym, Will Martin, and Dominique van der Mensbrugghe. (2006). Market
and Welfare Implications of the Doha Reform Scenarios. In Agricultural
Trade Reform and the Doha Development Agenda, ed., Kym Anderson and
Will Martin. London and Washington: Palgrave Macmillan and World Bank).
It is important to note that these estimates are roughly $100 billion
lower than earlier World Bank projections, largely due to updated data
sets.(World Bank. (2002). Global Economic Prospects 2002: Making Trade
Work for the Poor. Washington). As we have noted, we believe the LINKAGE
model (van der Mensbrugghe, Dominique, 2005, "Linkage Technical
Reference Document." Development Prospects Group, The World Bank)
used to estimate these gains is based on a series of unrealistic assumptions.
A classic and important example of the sort of unrealistic yet sweeping
assumptions the World Bank adopts in its LINKAGE model has to do with
the macroeconomic consequences of a reduction in tariffs. Obviously,
such a reduction will result in lost government revenues and either
a small budget surplus or a higher deficit.
The World Bank model assumes that the government's budget surplus or
deficit does not change - in other words, that they raise other taxes
to make up the shortfall - and that the macroeconomic impact is neutral.
In another important case, the World Bank also assumes that labour is
fully employed, even though a tariff reduction in some industries would
cost jobs that may very likely be hard to replace through employment
in other industries, even if those industries benefit.
Aside from assumptions that governments do not run budget deficits and
that labour is always fully employed, the World Bank also assumes that
trade is always balanced and that, in conjunction, the exchange rate
is free to adjust, ensuring the quick and painless correction of the
trade deficit. Thus, given this set of assumptions ensures that the
macroeconomic indicators - employment, government deficit, and trade
deficit - do not impact model outcomes.
A second set of similarly controversial assumptions concerns the details
about how the model is put in place. These are a bit more technical.
Here, the World Bank assumes that domestic product and imports combine
into "one good with distinct characteristics," leading some
consumers to substitute one for the other following price changes. It
also assumes that reduced tariffs will trigger productivity gains over
time, when in fact Ricardian theory predicts only static or one-time
gains. In sum, these are strong assumptions that we believe are unwarranted.
Most important, recent research that relaxes a number of these assumptions
predicts benefits much smaller than in the World Bank studies, and also
shows that a number of countries and sectors in the developing world
will lose. A recent model by the Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace, with more realistic assumptions, estimates a $168 billion global
economic gain over time, or $43 billion per year, as a result of full
liberalization. This is equivalent to a rounding error in a $44 trillion
world economy (Polaski, 2006). Such limited gains, along with the potential
damage to individual sectors and developing economies, is likely contributing
to the inability to reach agreement in the Doha Round.
Our study employs a revised CGE model representing sub-Saharan Africa
and the rest of the world. Our modelling and simulation strategy is
to mirror the essential structure of the World Bank's LINKAGE model.
However, instead of focusing on dis-aggregating the global economy in
scores of countries and sectors, we aim to shed light on the implications
of assumptions.
Thus, in order to be able to critique LINKAGE, we replicate several
aspects of the model, while making some changes that are required for
such an effort. Specifically, we analyse only two regions with three
sectors that characterize interactions between rich and poor countries.
We take a static viewpoint, thus we do not assume that efficiency gains
trigger productivity and growth over time. We also experiment with varying
elasticity values, so that we can avoid the pitfalls of unequivocally
choosing sides in an area with conflicting empirical evidence.
Our baseline scenario features lower elasticity values because we think
they are more realistic. Most importantly, however, we do not treat
unemployment and the trade deficit and government debt as constant,
but allow them to vary. Relaxing these assumptions marks a major departure
from the World Bank's model and hopefully makes our results of some
value to policymakers, who may be concerned with such macroeconomic
implications as higher unemployment (which, to repeat, the World Bank
model assumes away).
Our findings suggest that the effects of multilateral trade liberalization
with these assumptions are quite different than the World Bank concludes.
To take but one example, if taxes on households are raised to offset
the loss of government revenue from the tariff cut, then consumption
of clothing overall may not rise adequately unless elasticities based
on price are very high.
Sub-Saharan Africa may thus face welfare losses even in an otherwise
optimistic situation. Our revised CGE model also suggests that Africa,
though not the developed world, would probably face a deteriorating
trade balance. When the analysis allows for a changing rather than a
fixed government budget deficit, the African public balance often deteriorates,
whereas the rest of the world's fiscal position improves.
Finally, our study finds that if employment and income are variable,
they may increase in sub-Saharan Africa, but do so in tandem with mounting
trade deficits and foreign debt, rendering such advances temporary.
Rather than rejoicing about the former, the latter foreshadow the potential
of debt and currency crises, making it all the more important to take
the macroeconomic aspects of liberalization into account.
Policy Implications
We do not intend to engage in the debate about the exact magnitude of
welfare losses or gains from a likely Doha agreement. We believe that
claims for such precision are unwarranted by these models. Rather, our
aim is to analyse the typical CGE trade model, and to present a simplified
model with more realistic assumptions and dynamics.
Our research suggests that developing countries would be ill-advised
to follow the radical recommendations of the World Bank's liberalization
strategy insofar as it rests on results from the current trade models.
At this point, there is every reason to demand serious revisions to
proposals from developed countries prior to any revival of the Doha
process.
We appeal for more honest simulation strategies that produce a variety
of plausible outcomes. Such models would better enable policy makers
to assess the different scenarios for themselves.
Simulation results cannot be considered in a vacuum, and results alone
do not provide sufficient evidence for key decision-making. CGE models
can be useful quantitative supplements to thought experiments about
the importance of different potential causal linkages among economic
variables at the country or world level. However, mechanically churning
out projections of welfare gains subject to a single set of causal assumptions
and parameter values is a fundamental misuse of this tool.
[* Lance Taylor is the Director of the Schwartz Center for Economic
Policy Analysis (SCEPA) and the Arnhold Professor of International Cooperation
and Development at the New School for Social Research. Rudiger von Arnim
is a Research Assistant. This SCEPA Policy Note is based on their 2006
paper for Oxfam International titled, "Modeling the Impact of Trade
Liberalization: A Critique of Computable General Equilibrium Models."]
BACK
TO MAIN | ONLINE
BOOKSTORE | HOW TO ORDER
|