Curbing
hot capital flows to protect the real economy
Developing
countries are once again the destination for speculative capital flows,
with inflows reaching pre-crisis levels, leading to currency appreciation
and asset bubbles. Many of these nations are deploying prudential capital
regulations to stem these flows. However, this may only be a partial
remedy to the problem - such measures should be coupled with action
by the developed countries in order to fully steer capital to productive
use and to avoid future crises.
Stephany
Griffith-Jones & Kevin P Gallager
AS nations
across Asia and Latin America still
have a long way to go in terms of economic growth, foreign investment
is quite welcome. The problem is that the sheer volume and composition
of these flows implies that a large part does not go into productive
investment. Mass inflows of short-term capital are causing asset bubbles
and currency appreciation in developing countries, which make macroeconomic
policy difficult and raise the risk of future crises. Short-term inflows
are flocking to the developing world largely through the mechanism of
the carry trade.
Another
crisis in the making?
Since the
global financial crisis began, interest rates have been very low in
the United States
and in other industrialised nations. Increased US
liquidity can trigger investors to pull dollars out of the US and invest them in nations with
higher interest rates for rapid return, often using derivatives. Known
as the carry trade, such speculative short-term flows push up the value
of emerging-market currencies and create asset bubbles.
It is for
this reason that the US was criticised at the 2010 summit of the G20
major economies group in Seoul. For example, Brazil, with interest rates over 10%, has seen
an appreciation of over 30% due in part to the carry trade, and was
most vocal in Seoul.
This is a problem in many emerging and even poor developing countries,
like Uganda,
with excessive short-term inflows.
Figures 1
and 2 exhibit capital inflows into emerging Asia and Latin
America since the financial crisis. Immediately after the
crisis there was a massive and destabilising retreat of capital from
the developing countries to the 'safety' of the industrialised world.
However, as both these figures show, emerging markets are again a fruitful
destination for speculative capital.
In Figure
1, inflows (non-foreign direct investment or non-FDI) of capital into
emerging Asia are juxtaposed with the
appreciation of the South Korean won. In Figure 2, capital flows to
Latin America are followed by appreciation
of the Brazilian real. These two currencies have appreciated more than
30% since the onset of the crisis.
Responding
to excessive inflows
Emerging and
developing economies are following a set of options to stem the tide,
one of which is to engage in prudential capital account management by
taxing or putting unremunerated reserve requirements on capital inflows.
While this is not a panacea, it does help to provide greater monetary
policy autonomy to these countries. This is essential as their growth
rates are high at present, and it is crucial for them to avoid not only
inflation in goods and services, but also asset price bubbles and overvalued
exchange rates.
Many nations
such as Brazil, China,
Argentina, Taiwan,
Thailand, South Korea, Peru
and Indonesia
have put in place various forms of capital account regulations to limit
excessive inflows. Such controls have been recently sanctioned by the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) - a landmark shift.
These measures
follow a mountain of economic evidence in academia and by the international
financial institutions, most notably the National Bureau of Economic
Research in the US, the IMF, the United Nations, and
the Asian Development Bank. In February 2010, IMF economists published
a staff position note empirically showing that capital controls not
only work but 'were associated with avoiding some of the worst growth
outcomes' of the current economic crisis. The paper concluded that the
'...use of capital controls - in addition to both prudential and macroeconomic
policy - is justified as part of the policy toolkit to manage inflows'
(Ostry et al 2010: 5).
This IMF note
singles out measures such as taxes on short-term debt (like those put
in place by Brazil) or requirements whereby inflows of short-term debt
need to be accompanied by a deposit to be placed in the central bank
for a certain period of time (as practised by nations such as Chile,
Colombia and Thailand). The goal of these measures - which are often
turned on when capital flows become excessive and turned off when things
cool down - is to prevent massive inflows of hot money that can appreciate
the exchange rate and threaten the macroeconomic stability of a nation.
The IMF's
findings could not have come at a better time. Following the latest
round of quantitative easing (QE2) by the US Federal Reserve (Fed),
the carry trade is again bringing speculative capital to developing
countries that could disrupt their recovery from the crisis. As pointed
out by Ocampo (2010), '...monetary expansion may be largely ineffective
in the country that undertakes it, but can generate large negative externalities
on others.'


Barriers
to effective controls
To make the
proper deployment of capital controls effective, however, at least three
obstacles need to be overcome. First, after a time, investors often
evade prudential capital management through derivatives and other instruments.
Second, US trade and investment agreements make capital controls difficult
to implement. Third, speculative capital can still wreak havoc because
hot money passes by countries that successfully deploy controls and
flows into nations that do not.
Brazil
started imposing a tax on hot money inflows in October 2009 and has
been finetuning them ever since, in part because of the volume of flows,
but also because the regulation was being evaded. Some investors have
avoided controls by disguising short-term capital as FDI through currency
swaps and other derivatives and by purchasing American depositary receipts
(ADRs).
ADRs are issued
by US banks and allow investors to buy shares of firms outside the US
- enabling investors to purchase Brazilian shares in New
York and thereby avoiding controls in Brazil. In a step in the right direction
Brazil
moved to levy a 1.5% tax on ADRs to stem speculation around the earlier
controls. Now a Brazilian bank or investor that deposits shares with
foreign banks will be charged the tax.
Since 2003,
US trade and investment treaties have made prudential management of
capital accounts by developing-country trading partners difficult, if
not impossible. The treaties have mandated the free flow of capital
to and from countries - for instance, in trade deals with Chile, Peru
and Singapore.
In the case of Singapore
and Chile,
the countries resisted these measures, but ultimately agreed to the
treaties. Pending deals with Colombia
and South Korea
would also ban prudential capital controls. Other higher-income countries
and trade partners - such as Canada
and Japan
- grant countries the right to use the macroeconomic tool or at least
grant exemptions to prevent or mitigate crises.
The third
problem, which may be the most difficult, is that capital will simply
flow by those nations that successfully deploy controls to nations that
do not. Some economists, such as former IMF economist Arvind Subramanian,
propose full-fledged coordinated capital controls among all emerging-market
economies to circumvent the problem. This is a justifiable solution
to the coordination problem but of course not all emerging markets will
agree to coordinate. We propose attacking the problem at its source.
Regulating
the carry trade
Actions taken
by developing countries on their capital accounts may not be enough
as the wall of money presently coming towards them is so large and potentially
volatile. Therefore it may be desirable to complement these measures
with action by the countries where the capital is coming from, especially
from the US - due
to QE2 and the general ease of US monetary policy. Given that the
majority of the carry trade will in the near future come from the US, it
could start regulating the outflow of capital from the carry trade.
The US
could introduce measures to discourage the carry-trade flows to the
rest of the world, and especially to developing countries. This could
be done by taxing such flows. Also, foreign exchange derivatives that
mimic such transactions could have high margin requirements to discourage
them.
Such a measure
would benefit the US economy as the purpose of QE2 is to encourage
increased bank lending and lower interest rates in the US and not for funds to be channelled
abroad. It would also benefit emerging markets, whose economies are
being harmed by excessive short-term inflows that could cause future
crises. It would be a big win-win for the world economy.
The results
of the recent US
elections make it very difficult for the US to currently pursue the first best
policy to keep its economy recovering - further fiscal expansion. As
Keynes showed, and we have seen during numerous crises, private investment
and consumption will not recover on their own - due to both over-leveraging
and lack of confidence - without the stimulus of aggregate demand, which
only governments can give in these circumstances. Once the recovery
is on track, fiscal policy needs to contract to avoid both overheating
and excessive public debt.
The Fed has
already brought the short-term interest rate to zero, so Ben Bernanke,
to his credit, has ventured into the emergency toolkit. The Fed chairman
should be applauded for his willingness to think past convention. As
one of the last policymakers in developed countries with significant
economic power, he is now almost the sole voice for an expansionary
economic policy.
However, on
its own, QE2 may not be enough to restore the US
economy to growth. It will contribute to further overheating of asset
prices in the emerging economies, which could complicate macroeconomic
management for them now and also increase the risk of future crises.
To ensure
QE2 helps the US economy to grow, mechanisms need
to be found to channel the additional liquidity created by the Fed as
credit to the real economy. The key is to expand credit to small and
medium-sized enterprises, starved of funds at present, and to finance
large investments in infrastructure, including that required to generate
clean energy. Institutional innovations may be necessary to achieve
this, such as the creation of an infrastructure fund.
Internationally,
if the US dug into the emergency toolbox
again, it could place prudent capital regulations on the outflow of
speculative capital via the carry trade. This might help avoid future
crises in the destination countries, which would harm not only them,
but also the US and
the world economy.
Controls on
short-term outflows would facilitate the liquidity created by the Fed
staying in the US and having a better chance of going
towards productive investment. Such investment could help developing
countries via trade rather than causing speculative capital to flow
to emerging markets and wreak havoc on their financial systems and economies.
Road to
the G20
Reorienting
capital flows for productive development should be a priority as world
leaders prepare for the next G20 meeting in Paris. Prudential capital
account regulations, deployed in both the industrialised and the developing
world, should be examined as a partial remedy to the problem.
It is promising
that the French Finance Minister Christine Lagarde said in early December,
'Capital controls should only be done.in case of a surge of capital
flows and in a coordinated fashion. There needs to be a referee.' Her
emphasis on coordinated capital controls is significant as France heads the G20 for 2011.
To rectify
some of the problems related to capital flows, industrialised nations
(especially the US) should
consider regulating the carry trade and providing safeguards in their
trade treaties to allow developing nations to deploy prudential regulation.
Developing countries should also put in place prudential regulations.
The Financial Stability Board, as well as national regulatory authorities,
should oversee them and take measures to limit avoidance.
Stephany
Griffith-Jones is with the Initiative for Policy Dialogue, Columbia University.
Kevin P Gallagher teaches international relations at Boston University.
This article is reproduced from Economic & Political Weekly (Vol.
46, No. 3, January 15-21, 2011). Shorter versions have been published
in the Guardian (18 November 2010) and in the Financial Times (17 December
2010).
References
IMF (2010):
World Economic Outlook: Recovery, Risk and Rebalancing, October (Washington
DC: IMF).
Ocampo, Jose
Antonio (2010): 'The Case for Taxing Forex Transactions', Shanghai Daily,
20 November, available at http://www.shanghaidaily.com/sp/article/2010/201011/20/article_455082.htm
Ostry, Jonathan
D, Atish R Ghosh, Karl Habermeier, Marcos Chamon, Mahvash S Qureshi
and Dennis B S Reinhardt (2010): 'Capital Inflows: The Role of Controls',
IMF Staff Position Note, 19 February, SPN/10/04.
*Third
World Resurgence No. 245/246, January/February 2011, pp 24-26
|