TWN
Info Service on Health Issues (Oct17/05)
17 October 2017
Third World Network
How
pharma firms & corporate hospitals fleece patients
by K M Gopakumar
http://www.dnaindia.com/analysis/column-how-pharma-firms-corporate-hospitals-fleece-patients-2551632
The notification includes high volume MDs such as syringes, IV cannula,
catheters etc., which are currently sold to patients at 500 per cent
to 100 per cent trade margins
The National Pharmaceutical Pricing Authority (NPPA), using its powers
under the Drugs Price Control Order 2013, capped the prices of cardiovascular
stents and knee implants. NPPA has powers to fix the prices of all
medical devices (MD) notified as drugs under the Drugs and Cosmetics
Act. The price of stents is fixed at Rs 7, 260 Bare Metal Stents (BMS)
and Rs 29, 600 Drug Eluting Stents (DES). Price of the cobalt chromium
knee implant is fixed at Rs 54, 720 against an earlier MRP of Rs 1,58,324.
The price of titanium and oxidised zirconium is fixed at Rs 76,660
from Rs 2,49,000.
As expected, foreign manufacturers of these MDs, organisations linked
to these entities and doctors associated with the corporate hospitals
came out against NPPA’s decision. These opponents of the decision
do not contest the prime objective of the price control i.e., ensuring
access at an affordable price. The main objection is the detrimental
effect of price control on innovation and the denial of innovative
MDs to patients in future. They argue that the price ceiling reduces
the profit margin and thus undermines the resource allocation for
innovation. It is important to look at the real beneficiary high prices
of MDs in India before examining the merits of the argument.
The data gathered by NPPA shows that hospitals were the main beneficiary
of the pre-price control stent market. As per NPPA data hospitals
used to obtain 436 per cent margin from patients for (BMS) and 654
per cent margin in the case of DES against MRP. NPPA data also reveals
that the minimum (Rs 16,749) and maximum landing price of imported
DES (Rs 40,820) and the minimum and maximum MRP for the same were
Rs 40,000 and Rs 1,98,000. Similarly, in the case of knee implants,
NPPA found that against a minimum and maximum landing price of Rs
23,408 and Rs 65,781, the minimum and maximum MRP were Rs 59,091 and
Rs 4,13,059. Hospitals used to obtain an average of 178 per cent margin
from the patients. While fixing the prices of stents and knee implants,
NPPA also fixed 8 per cent as the margin hospitals can charge from
patients. Thus, the real loser of the price ceiling is hospitals,
not the manufactures.
The argument against price control in the interest of innovation assumes
that all innovations are good for patients. In reality, patients do
not benefit from all innovations in MD or medicines. Some innovations
not only fail to provide any benefit, but also endanger a patients’
life or safety. For instance, Abbotts’s much-hyped bio-absorbable
stents were withdrawn from the market due to reports of adverse effect
on patients. Therefore, medical innovations should be assessed on
the basis of the patient outcome in light of evidence emerging from
the clinical trial and health technology assessment. The Minutes of
the NPPA decision clearly show that it considered such evidence while
fixing the price of stents and knee implants. In the absence of evidence,
NPPA fixed the same price for DES and bio-absorbable stents. NPPA
also rejected claims for a differential price for DES made of steel
and cobalt. In the absence of evidence of superiority, NPPA fixed
a 40 per cent trade margin for cobalt chromium knee implants against
a 30 per cent trade margin for titanium and oxidised zirconium, which
is an innovative product. Further, NPPA rightly observed that 40 per
cent or 30 per cent trade margin with ceiling on trade margins to
distributors and hospitals are enough to finance future innovation.
Advocates against price ceiling also ignore the following facts on
medical innovation while arguing against price control. First, expenditure
for innovations on the existing product always cost less than the
development of a new product. Second, manufacturers based in developed
countries invest for the new product development and developing country
manufactures mainly carry out follow-on innovations. The cost of new
product development and resource for future R&D often recouped
from the developed country market. Third, there is no transparency
with regard to the cost of R&D. Companies often inflate their
R&D expenditure. Four, the initial cost of bio-medical R&D
usually comes from public funding. As a result, the entire cost of
R&D is not borne by the innovator.
Often, hospitals and doctors push costly imported MDs, offering high
margins to patients by lying on the added benefits without any evidence.
These actors also force domestic manufacturers to fix a high MRP and
thus eliminate the opportunities to generate competition in the market.
The actions of NPPA thus create a level playing field for the domestic
manufactures and generate competition in the market.
In the name of innovation, one should not support high prices, which
is mainly pocketed by hospitals in the case of MDs. Such an approach
compromises access to MDs and promotes profiteering at the cost of
right to health and right to make use of science and its applications.
The government should expand price control to cover other notified
MDs notified under the Drugs and Cosmetics Act. The notification includes
high volume MDs such as syringes, IV cannula, catheters etc., which
are currently sold to patients at 500 per cent to 100 per cent trade
margins.
The author is a researcher associated with the Third World Network