|
||
TWN
Info Service on Finance and Development (May08/06) THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL TURMOIL AND ASIAN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES After
about six years of exceptional growth, the world economy has now entered
a period of instability and uncertainty due to a global financial turmoil
triggered by the sub-prime crisis in the The crisis is comprehensive and global, encompassing the banking sector, securities and currency markets, and institutional and individual investors in most parts of the world. Below
is an analysis of the global financial turmoil by Yilmaz Akyuz, former
Director in UNCTAD. It is a summary of a paper he presented at ESCAP
in The paper analyses the potential effects of the global financial turmoil on Asian countries, particularly through finance and trade mechanisms. It also discusses the policy options for Asian countries to respond to the effects. With
best wishes The
Global Financial Turmoil and Asian Developing Countries After
about six years of exceptional growth, the world economy has now entered
a period of instability and uncertainty due to a global financial turmoil
triggered by the sub-prime crisis in the Current
difficulties, however, are not unrelated to forces driving the preceding
expansion. From the early years of the decade the world economy went
through a period of easy money as interest rates in major industrial
countries were brought down to historically low levels and international
liquidity expanded rapidly. In the Global liquidity and an increase in the risk appetite, rather than improvements in fundamentals, have also been the main reason for a generalized and sustained surge in capital flows to emerging markets. They have given a boost to growth in the recipient countries, but also generated fragility and imbalances, including unsustainable currency appreciations and current account deficits, and credit, asset and investment bubbles, which now render them vulnerable, in different ways and degrees, to shocks from the sub-prime crisis. The
crisis is comprehensive and global, encompassing the banking sector,
securities and currency markets, and institutional and individual investors
in most parts of the world. The bursting of the bubble has left the
The
evolution of the world economy now depends crucially on the impact of
the crisis on growth in the However,
for the first time in modern history hopes seem to be pinned on developing
countries for sustaining stability and growth in the world economy.
On the one hand, the Sovereign Wealth Funds (SWFs) from emerging markets
are increasingly looked at as stabilizing forces in financial markets
by providing capital to support troubled banks in the CRISIS, GROWTH AND EXTERNAL ADJUSTMENT IN THE UNITED STATES There
is great uncertainty as to whether the But
it is agreed that monetary easing cannot fully resolve the difficulties
since this is, in essence, a solvency crisis. Again, the fiscal package
may not be enough to make up for cuts in private spending. It now appears
that the The
crisis could well produce a swift retrenchment in private consumption,
reduction in the savings gap and correction of external deficits in
the RECENT
CAPITAL FLOWS AND VULNERABILITY IN A
key question in The
recent record in Interventions designed to absorb excess foreign currency due to the surge in capital inflows and/or current account surpluses have been broadly successful in stabilizing exchange rates in the region. But their effect on domestic liquidity could not always be fully sterilized, and this has resulted in rapid domestic credit expansion. Outside
Asian
countries have received, in different degrees, relatively large inflows
of speculative capital. Foreign presence in equity markets and the banking
sector has increased rapidly, raising volatility and the risk of contagion.
Capital inflows, together with expansionary monetary policy, have created
bubbles in stock and property markets in several countries, notably
in Many Asian countries have been facing macroeconomic policy dilemmas mainly because they have chosen to keep their economies open to financial inflows, rather than imposing tighter counter-cyclical measures of control. Capital accounts in the region are more open today than they were during the Asian crisis. The main response to large capital inflows has been to liberalize outward investment by residents. This is partly motivated by a desire to allow national firms to become important players in world markets through investment abroad, but there has also been considerable liberalization of portfolio outflows. The rationale of such a policy as a strategy for closer integration with global financial markets is highly contentious. As a short-term measure, it could be even more problematic since once introduced for cyclical reasons, it may not be easily rolled back when conditions change. FINANCIAL CONTAGION AND SHOCKS Growth
projections have been constantly revised downward since summer 2007
as financial difficulties became more visible. Still, none of the most
recent baseline projections by the IMF, World Bank, United Nations,
the ADB and the IIF envisage a sharp drop in income in the Asian economies do not appear to have large direct exposure to securitised assets linked to high-risk lending and the financial impact of the crisis is likely to be transmitted through changes in the risk appetite and capital flows. These would be coming on top of domestic fragilities associated with credit and asset bubbles in some of the key countries in the region. The
question of sustainability of these bubbles had been raised even before
the sub-prime turmoil, and they have now become even more fragile, susceptible
to a sharp correction. By itself this may not lower growth by more than
a couple of percentage points in According
to the most recent projections, the crisis would not have much impact
on private capital flows to emerging markets in the current year; there
would be some decline in bank lending, largely compensated by increases
in equity flows. It is also argued that capital flows may even accelerate
if Europe joins the It is quite likely that international investors now start differentiating among countries to a much greater extent than has been the case in recent years. Those with large external deficits, high levels of debt and inadequate reserves may face a sudden stop and even reversal of capital flows and sharp increases in spreads. Given massive amounts of reserves, even a generalized exit of capital from emerging markets would not create serious payments difficulties for most Asian countries, and the impact would be felt primarily in domestic financial markets. Such an exit could be triggered by a widespread flight toward quality with investors taking refuge in the safety of government bonds in advanced countries or a need to liquidate holdings in emerging markets in order to cover mounting losses and margin calls. TRADE
LINKAGES AND GROWTH IN In
general, trade shocks from the sub-prime crisis are not expected to
result in a sharp decline of growth in This line of thinking clearly focuses on the impact of exports on aggregate demand, rather than on the foreign exchange constraint. It is implicitly assumed that the countries affected can continue to maintain import growth despite reduced export earnings. This would pose no major problem for those running large current account surpluses. Others with deficits, however, would need to rely increasingly on capital inflows and/or draw on their reserves in order to finance the widening gap between imports and exports. This
simple arithmetic is further complicated by a number of factors. First,
the trade impact of the crisis depends on how other Asian export markets
are affected. A sharp slowdown in Europe can hurt growth in Asia since
exports to that region account for 7 per cent of GDP in Those
supplying intermediate goods to POLICY CHALLENGES Whatever the nature and extent of contagion and shocks from the crisis, it is important to avoid destabilizing feedbacks between real and financial sectors. A sharp drop in exports together with a rapid correction in asset prices could bring down growth considerably which can, in turn, threaten the solvency of the banking system given the high degree of leverage of firms in some countries. The appropriate policy response would be to expand domestic demand through fiscal stimulus. If difficulties emerge in the financial sector, it would also be necessary to provide lender-of-last-resort financing. Nevertheless, policy interventions should smooth, rather than prevent correction in asset prices and facilitate restructuring in over-expanded sectors. If capital inflows continue at their recent pace or accelerate, a policy of controlled appreciation of the yuan combined with tighter control over inflows and a long-term strategy of expansion of Chinese direct investment abroad, including in developing countries would appear to be a desirable response. But perhaps the greatest challenge would be to secure expansion of the internal market based on a more rapid growth of consumption than has hitherto been the case. Since
the early years of the decade, consumption has constantly lagged behind
income and investment, and its share fell below 40 per cent of GDP -
almost half of the figure in the This is largely a reflection of the imbalance between profits and wages. Despite registering impressive increases, wages have lagged behind productivity growth and their share in value-added has declined in recent years. There are also relatively large precautionary savings from wage incomes because of absence of adequate public health care, education and social security services. All these imbalances are presumably among the problems that Premier Wen Jiabao was referring to when he pointed out at the National People’s Congress in March 2007 that “the biggest problem with China’s economy is that the growth is unstable, unbalanced, uncoordinated and unsustainable.” They
need to be addressed independent of the shocks from the sub-prime crisis
if In
other Asian economies closely linked through production networks, domestic
stimulus would be needed to offset a reduction in exports to On the external side, Asian emerging markets appear to have sustainable current account positions as well as relatively large stocks of reserves to weather any potential worsening of their trade balances as a result of a slowdown in exports. Countries with current account deficits could see them rise further as exports slow down and growth of income and imports is sustained. Given their relatively high levels of reserves, this should cause no serious problem. However, if slowdown in markets abroad is accompanied by a sudden stop or reversal of capital flows, these countries could be restricted in their ability to respond positively to external shocks. In some of these cases twin structural deficits in fiscal and external accounts would thus need greater attention for reducing vulnerability to such shocks. Low-income countries dependent on official flows are highly vulnerable to a sharp deterioration in global economic conditions and in many of them, including small island economies, current account deficits could rise rapidly as a result of a slowdown in trade in goods and services. These countries should thus be able to have access to additional IMF financing through augmentation of resources made available under PRGF arrangements and the Exogenous Shocks Facility. REGIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL COOPERATION A
reasonable degree of consistency would be needed among policy responses
of individual countries in It
is, therefore, important to engage in intra-regional consultations in
exchange rate policies and explore more durable regional currency arrangements.
The experience of There are other, more flexible, options available. Complementary arrangements could also be considered, including a common set of measures to curb excessive capital inflows, formal arrangements for macroeconomic policy coordination, surveillance of regional financial markets and capital flows, and extended intra-regional short-term credit facilities based on the Chiang Mai initiative already under way. Current conditions demonstrate once again that when policies falter in regulating financial institutions and markets, there is no limit to the damage that they can inflict on an economy and that in a world of closely integrated markets, every major financial crisis has global repercussions. This means that shortcomings in national systems of financial rules and regulations are of international concern - particularly those in major advanced economies because of their significant global repercussions. So far, piecemeal initiatives in international fora such as the BIS, the IMF and the Financial Stability Forum have not been very effective in preventing recurrence of virulent global financial crises. A fundamental collective rethinking with full participation of developing countries is thus needed for harnessing financial markets and reducing systemic and global instability. *
Yilmaz Akyuz is a former director of the Globalization and Development
Strategies Division of UNCTAD. This is a summary of a paper presented
at the Ministerial segment of the ESCAP (UN Economic and Social Council
for Asia Pacific) session in
|