|
||
The implications of the new issues in the WTO A leading trade expert analyses the real motives behind the drive by the North to push the new issues of investment, competition, government procurement and e-commerce on to the agenda of the WTO Ministerial meeting in Seattle, and suggests some possible responses by the South to this move. by Bhagirath Lal Das Introduction NEW issues have been frequently entering the GATT/WTO system over the last two decades, invariably at the instance of major developed countries. The current new issues under consideration are: investment, competition, government procurement and electronic commerce. There are different levels of objectives and scope of consideration in these subjects. In the area of government procurement, the exercise is aimed at developing elements for an agreement on transparency, whereas in the areas of investment and competition policy, the exercise is limited to the study of their relationship with trade. In the case of competition, the study process will examine the issues raised by countries on the relationship. In electronic commerce, already an interim agreement has been reached to have a standstill on duty (meaning thereby zero duty) for 18 months from May 1998 onward. The exercise now is to examine what is to be done thereafter. Comprehensive examination by developing countries of the three areas under study in the WTO should naturally be aimed at:
Long-term implications The examination of the implications should be based not only on the immediate indications of the objectives of the developed countries, which were the main proponents of these subjects, but also on their declared long-term expectations in these areas. For example, in the area of government procurement, though they have reluctantly limited the exercise to transparency, they have often made it clear that their aim is to enhance market access for their goods and services. It is necessary to keep all these aspects in view while considering each of these areas. Foreign investment is no doubt generally desirable, particularly in developing countries; but the objectives of the major developed countries in introducing this subject in the WTO do not appear to be aimed at enhancing investment in developing countries. These are, in fact, aimed at restraining the discretion and flexibility of developing-country governments in respect of putting conditions on foreign investments; thereby ensuring free and unfettered operation of foreign investors in developing countries. Their aim appears to be centred on protecting the rights of foreign investors, rather than ensuring the flow of investment into the developing countries. Foreign investment may be necessary and useful in developing countries for: (i) augmenting investment, (ii) supplementing the inflow of foreign exchange and (iii) rapid upgradation of technology. Apart from foreign aid, there are three broad channels for this purpose, viz., loans, portfolio investment and foreign direct investment (FDI). The last is considered preferable to the first two, mainly for two reasons. First, loans have to be repaid, and thus involve outflow of foreign exchange at a later date. Second, portfolio investment, by its very nature, may not be stable and dependable. Cautions But while preferring FDI, a country has to be cautious about the following implications:
FDI can still be very useful and the adverse implications mentioned above can be mitigated to a great extent, if it is put to use for some long- term gain. For example:
But this will not come about automatically, because it may not - in fact, in many cases, it will not - coincide with the first choice of the investor, whose main priorities naturally are: (i) quick profit from investment, and (ii) production with the least of worries. The choice of the product and that of the location of the production unit will be guided by these concerns. More often, it may result in: (i) production in non-priority sectors and (ii) units located in already developed regions. The necessary consequences will be: wastage of foreign exchange and regional disparities in development. These and other adverse effects can be minimised if the host governments exercise their discretion to:
The main aim of the developed countries in proposing this subject for negotiation in the WTO is to curtail the discretion of the host countries, so that the foreign investors have total freedom of operation. If such a move does succeed, the dangers mentioned above will certainly materialise. As mentioned earlier, the proposals for negotiations on investment in the WTO are not really aimed at enhancing investment in developing countries, for which quite different steps are needed; instead, the main objective is to ensure and protect the rights of investors through multilateral binding commitments which would be enforceable through the Dispute Settlement Understanding of the WTO, particularly through the provision of cross-retaliation. For attracting FDI, it is not necessary for developing countries to participate in a multilateral investment agreement. What is really needed is that they have national legislation and procedures providing security and facility for foreign investment and they develop basic infrastructure in their countries for the installation and operation of production units. Competition policy Healthy competition is very much desirable, but the objective of the major developed countries in bringing this subject into the folds of the WTO seems more to aim at ensuring free and unhindered operation of their firms in developing countries, which may be adverse to the interests of developing countries. Healthy competition is desirable, as:
Conflicting interests But behind these simple features, there are certain conflicting interests, some illustrations of which are given below.
There has to be appropriate balance in all these cases of differing interests, and this balance should be worked out by various countries in the context of their own national objectives and priorities. Standards of competition in developing countries need not be similar to those in highly developed countries. The developing countries should formulate these policies based on their own development objectives and priorities and on their own perception of the balance between the needs of the consumers and the imperatives of the firms in their growth process. The main objective of the proponents of this subject in the WTO appears to be to restrain the discretion of individual countries and lay down rules for certain minimum standards of competition policy, particularly in developing countries. The possible implications are the following:
In this background, it appears necessary for the developing countries to retain their discretion and flexibility to:
Points for attention Apart from consideration by host governments of these domestic implications, the competition policy initiatives in an international or multilateral forum must concentrate on anti-competitive policies in relation to international trade. In particular, the following features need attention:
Then we also have the actions of governments which restrict competition. For example, governments impose restrictions in the form of countervailing duty, anti-dumping duty and safeguard action. There have been numerous cases of other restrictive measures in the past, e.g., grey-area measures and special sectoral arrangements. There is a need for consideration of all these matters in any possible multilateral framework on competition policy. Ways will have to be found to ensure that the former set of measures does not become sources of unnecessary harassment of developing countries and the latter set of measures does not occur in future at all. The current study process in the WTO should include all this in its consideration; and should have specific provisions relating to all these concerns in any operative conclusions, suggestions and actions. Government procurement The current exercise in the WTO covers the study of transparency in government-procurement practices and developing elements of an appropriate agreement on transparency. However, there are clear indications that major developed countries consider this only as an initial and interim step; for them, the real aim is to expand the market access of their entities in the area of government procurement. Hence, a good deal of caution is needed in handling this subject. Transparency in government procurement is desirable, particularly in developing countries, as it will help the process of widening the supply base and bring about improvement in the internal decision-making process in this area. However, special care needs to be taken by the developing countries on the following points in this exercise in the current WTO process:
No particular advantage A general point of caution is that this exercise should not be allowed to expand or be transformed into one on market access for the goods of developed countries. In this connection, it is important to note that the developed countries would very much like to introduce the obligations of most-favoured-nation (MFN) treatment and national treatment in this area. This is of no particular advantage to developing countries for the following reasons:
Hence, even if the facility is given to them to participate in the tenders for supply of goods for government procurement in developed countries, they will hardly be able to take advantage of it. As against it, there are certain distinct disadvantages of introducing the principles of MFN treatment and national treatment in their government procurement process. Some of these are the following:
It is worth remembering that the exclusion of government procurement from the MFN treatment and national treatment obligations is a part of the current rights and obligations in GATT 1994 (Article XVII.2 and Article III.8.a). As the developing countries are clearly not going to gain from introducing these provisions into the area of government procurement, they do not have to relinquish these rights. Electronic commerce Yet another new subject, viz., electronic commerce, has already jumped into the bandwagon of the WTO. A major developed country brought up this subject during the Ministerial Meeting in Geneva in May 1998 and an interim agreement was reached for zero duty as mentioned earlier. Now the pressure will be to continue with this agreement of zero duty for indefinite period. Missing the point Already there is some trade in tangible goods with the help of the electronic medium, e.g., ordering certain goods and making payment for them through this medium. But in this case, a tangible object, viz., the product in consideration, physically crosses the border; and hence the normal rules of the WTO will apply. But there are certain types of commercial transactions which do not necessarily entail crossing the border physically, e.g., the supply of the architectural design of a building or the engineering design of a machine through the electronic medium, etc. This is the type of transaction which is the subject of this new proposal. The suggestion is that governments should commit that they will not impose duties on such transactions. The rationale is not quite clear. One point which is made is that governments do not in any case impose taxes on such transactions at present; hence it is argued that little will change if a commitment is made to continue this practice in future. This argument misses the point that a commitment in the WTO will curtail the discretion to tax such transactions in future, and as such it is a specific concession. For developing countries, in fact, there is a good rationale for imposing entry taxes on such transactions. Some relevant points are given below as examples:
One important technical point which has to be noted is that the current proposal addresses itself not to any particular goods or services sector; it is targeted, rather, at a specific mode of conducting commercial transactions in goods and services. It therefore opens an entirely new chapter in the scope of work of the WTO. It does not appear desirable when so many subjects of the past have to be attended to and with the system quite strained by the load. What is, however, much more relevant is that the country making this request has not so far placed any offer on the table as a reciprocal concession in return for zero duty on electronic commerce. In the usual GATT/WTO practice, the country should make some offers of eliminating its duties on some products of interest to the others. In fact, the developing countries may themselves ask this country to eliminate its duties on the products of their interest. If such offers are made, the countries can then enter into serious negotiations. Right now, it is a totally one-sided affair, which appears very unfair and un-GATT-like. Thus, instead of asking the developing countries to agree to continue the zero duty, the proponent country should make its reciprocal offer, following which negotiations can take place. If developing countries agree to extend the current agreement, it will be a totally one-sided concession to the developed country which has made this proposal. It will be special and differential treatment in reverse. (Third World Resurgence No. 108/109, Aug-Sept 99) Bhagirath Lal Das was formerly India's Ambassador and Permanent Representative to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Later, he was Director of International Trade Programmes in the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD).
|